Karl Marx
Credit and Fictitious Capital (Chap. 3.25)
                                               Capital Vol. III Part V
         Division of Profit into Interest and Profit of Enterprise
                                             Interest-Bearing Capital

                               Chapter 25. Credit and Fictitious Capital


    An exhaustive analysis of the credit system and of the instruments which it creates for its own use (credit-money, etc.) lies beyond our plan. We merely wish to dwell here upon a few particular points, which are required to characterise the capitalist mode of production in general. We shall deal only with commercial and bank credit. The connection between the development of this form of credit and that of public credit will not be considered here.

    I have shown earlier (Buch I, Kap. III, 3, b [English edition: Ch. III, 3, b. — Ed.]) how the function of money as a means of payment, and therewith a relation of creditor and debtor between the producer and trader of commodities, develop from the simple circulation of commodities. With the development of commerce and of the capitalist mode of production, which produces solely with an eye to circulation, this natural basis of the credit system is extended, generalised, and worked out. Money serves here, by and large, merely as a means of payment, i.e., commodities are not sold for money, but for a written promise to pay for them at a certain date. For brevity's sake, we may put all these promissory notes under the general head of bills of exchange. Such bills of exchange, in their turn, circulate as means of payment until the day on which they fall due; and they form the actual commercial money. Inasmuch as they ultimately neutralise one another through the balancing of claims and debts, they act absolutely as money, although there is no eventual transformation into actual money. Just as these mutual advances of producers and merchants make up the real foundation of credit, so does the instrument of their circulation, the bill of exchange, form the basis of credit-money proper, of bank-notes, etc. These do not rest upon the circulation of money, be it metallic or government-issued paper money, but rather upon the circulation of bills of exchange.

    W. Leatham (banker of Yorkshire) writes in his Letters on the Currency, 2nd ed., London, 1840:

       "I find, then, the amount for the whole of the year of 1839...
      to be £528,493,842" (he assumed that the foreign bills of
      exchange made up about one-fifth of the total) "and the
      amount of bills out at one time in the above year, to be
      £132,123,460" (p. 56). The bills of exchange make up
      "one component part greater in amount than all the
      rest put together" (p. 3). "This enormous superstructure
      of bills of exchange rests (!) upon the base formed by
      the amount of bank-notes and gold, and when, by events,
      this base becomes too much narrowed, its solidity
      and very existence is endangered" (p. 8). "If I estimate
      the whole currency"

    (he means of the bank-notes)

       "and the amount of the liabilities of the Bank
      and country bankers, payable on demand, I find a sum of
      153 million, which, by law, can be converted into gold ...
      and the amount of gold to meet this demand" only 14
      million (p.11). "The bills of exchange are not ...
      placed under any control, except by preventing the abundance
      of money, excessive and low rates of interest or discount,
      which create a part of them, and encourage their great and
      dangerous expansion. It is impossible to decide what
      part arises out of real bonâ fide transactions,
      such as actual bargain and sale, or what part is fictitious
      and mere accommodation paper, that is, where one bill of
      exchange is drawn to take up another running, in order
      to raise a fictitious capital, by creating so much currency.
      In times of abundance and cheap money this I know reaches
      an enormous amount"

    (pp. 43-44). J.W. Bosanquet, Metallic, Paper and Credit Currency, London, 1842:

       "An average amount of payments to the extent of upwards of
      £3,000,000 is settled through the Clearing House

    (where the London bankers exchange due bills and filed cheques)

       every day of business in the year, and the daily amount
      of money required for the purpose is little more than £200,000"
      (p. 86).

    (In 1889, the total turnover of the Clearing House amounted to £7,618.75 million, which, in roughly 300 business days, averages £25½ million daily. — F. E.]

       "Bills of exchange act undoubtedly as currency,
      independent of money, inasmuch as they transfer property from
      hand to hand by endorsement" (p. 92). "It may be assumed
      that upon an average there are two endorsements upon every
      bill in circulation, and ... each bill performs two payments
      before it becomes due. Upon this assumption it would appear,
      that by endorsement alone property changed hands, by means of
      bills of exchange, to the value of twice five hundred and
      twenty-eight million, or £1,056,000,000, being at
      the rate of more than £3,000,000 per day, in the course of
      the year 1839. We may safely therefore conclude, that
      deposits and bills of exchange together, perform the
      functions of money, by transferring property from
      hand and to hand without the aid of money, to an extent daily
      of not less than £18,000,000" (p. 93).

    Tooke says the following about credit in general:

       "Credit, in its most simple expression, is the confidence
      which, well, or ill-founded, leads a person to entrust another
      with a certain amount of capital, in money, or in goods computed
      at a value in money agreed upon, and in each case payable at
      the expiration of a fixed term. In the case where the capital is
      lent in money, that is whether in bank-notes, or in a cash
      credit, or in an order upon a correspondent, an addition
      for the use of the capital of so much upon every £100 is made
      to the amount to be repaid. In the case of goods the value of
      which is agreed in terms of money, constituting a sale, the
      sum stipulated to be repaid includes a consideration
      for the use of the capital and for the risk, till the
      expiration of the period fixed for payment. Written obligations
      of payment at fixed dates mostly accompany these credits,
      and the obligations or promissory notes after date being
      transferable, form the means by which the lenders, if they
      have occasion for the use of their capital, in the shape whether
      of money or goods, before the expiration of the term of
      the bills they hold, are mostly enabled to borrow Or to
      buy on lower terms, by having their own credit strengthened
      by the names on the bills in addition to their own."
      (Inquiry into the Currency Principle, p. 87.)

    Ch. Coquelin, Du Crédit et des Banques dans L'Industrie, Revue des Deux Mondes, 1842, Tome 31:

       "In every country the majority of credit transactions takes
      place within the circle of industrial relations...
      The producer of the raw material advances it to the
      processing manufacturer, and receives from the latter
      a promise to pay on a certain day. The manufacturer, having
      completed his share of the work, in his turn advances his
      product on similar terms to another manufacturer,
      who has to process it further, and in this way credit
      stretches on and on, from one to the other, right up to
      the consumer. The wholesale dealer gives the retailer
      commodities on credit, while receiving credit from a
      manufacturer or commission agent. All borrow with one hand
      and lend with the other, sometimes money, but more frequently
      products. In this manner an incessant exchange of
      advances, which combine and intersect in all directions,
      takes place in industrial relations. The development
      of credit consists precisely in this multiplication and
      growth of mutual advances, and therein is the real seat
      of its power."

    The other side of the credit system is connected with the development of money-dealing, which, of course, keeps step under capitalist production with the development of dealing in commodity. We have seen in the preceding part (Chap. XIX) how the care of the reserve funds of businessmen, the technical operations of receiving and disbursing money, of international payments, and thus of the bullion trade, are concentrated in the hands of the money-dealers. The other side of the credit system — the management of interest-bearing capital, or money-capital, develops alongside this money-dealing as a special function of the money-dealers. Borrowing and lending money becomes their particular business. They act as middlemen between the actual lender and the borrower of money-capital. Generally speaking, this aspect of the banking business consists of concentrating large amounts of the loanable money-capital in the bankers' hands, so that, in place of the individual money-lender, the bankers confront the industrial capitalists and commercial capitalists as representatives of all moneylenders. They become the general managers of money-capital. On the other hand by borrowing for the entire world of commerce, they concentrate all the borrowers vis-à-vis all the lenders. A bank represents a centralisation of money-capital, of the lenders, on the one hand, and on the other a centralisation of the borrowers. Its profit is generally made by borrowing at a lower rate of interest than it receives in loaning.

    The loanable capital which the banks have at their disposal streams to them in various ways. In the first place, being the cashiers of the industrial capitalists, all the money-capital which every producer and merchant must have as a reserve fund, or receives in payment, is concentrated in their hands. These funds are thus converted into loanable money-capital. In this way, the reserve fund of the commercial world, because it is concentrated in a common treasury, is reduced to its necessary minimum, and a portion of the money-capital which would otherwise have to lie slumbering as a reserve fund, is loaned out and serves as interest-bearing capital. In the second place, the loanable capital of the banks is formed by the deposits of money-capitalists who entrust them with the business of loaning them out. Furthermore, with the development of the banking system, and particularly as soon as banks came to pay interest on deposits, money savings and the temporarily idle money of all classes were deposited with them. Small amounts, each in itself incapable of acting in the capacity of money-capital, merge together into large masses and thus form a money power. This aggregation of small amounts must be distinguished as a specific function of the banking system from its go-between activities between the money-capitalists proper and the borrowers. In the final analysis, the revenues, which are usually but gradually consumed, are also deposited with the banks.

    The loan is made (we refer here strictly to commercial credit) by discounting bills of exchange — by converting bills of exchange into money before they come due — and by advances of various kinds: direct advances on personal credit, loans against securities, such as interest-bearing paper, government paper, stocks of all sorts, and, notably, overdrafts against bills of lading, dock warrants, and other certified titles of ownership of commodities and overdrawing deposits, etc.

    The credit given by a banker may assume various forms, such as bills of exchange on other banks, cheques on them, credit accounts of the same kind, and finally, if the bank is entitled to issue notes — bank-notes of the bank itself. A bank-note is nothing but a draft upon a banker, payable at any time to the bearer, and given by the banker in place of private drafts. This last form of credit appears particularly important and striking to the layman, first, because this form of credit-money breaks out of the confines of mere commercial circulation into general circulation, and serves there as money; and because in most countries the principal banks issuing notes, being a peculiar mixture of national and private banks, actually have the national credit to back them, and their notes are more or less legal tender; because it is apparent here that the banker deals in credit itself, a bank-note being merely a circulating token of credit. But the banker also has to do with credit in all its other forms, even when he advances the cash money deposited with him. In fact, a bank-note simply represents the coin of wholesale trade, and it is always the deposit which carries the most weight with banks. The best proof of this is furnished by the Scottish banks.

    Special credit institutions, like special forms of banks, need no further consideration for our purpose.

       "The business of bankers ... may be divided into two
      branches... One branch of the banker's business is
      to collect capital from those who have not
      immediate employment for it, and to distribute or transfer
      it to those who have. The other branch is to receive
      deposits of the incomes of their customers, and to pay
      out the amount, as it is wanted for expenditure by the
      latter in the objects of their consumption... The former
      being a circulation of capital, the latter of currency... "
      — "One relates to the concentration of capital
      on the one hand and the distribution of it on the
      other, the other is employed in administering the circulation
      for local purposes of the district." Tooke, Inquiry
      into the Currency Principle, pp. 36, 37.

We shall revert to this passage later, in Chapter XXVIII.

    Reports of Committees, Vol. VIII. Commercial Distress, Vol. 11, Part I, 1847-48, Minutes of Evidence. (Further quoted as Commercial Distress, 1847-48.) In the forties, when discounting bills of exchange in London, 21-day drafts of one bank on another were often accepted in lieu of banknotes. (Testimony of J. Pease, country banker, Nos. 4638 and 4645.) According to the same report, bankers were in the habit of giving such bills of exchange regularly in payment to their customers whenever money was tight. If the receiver wanted bank-notes, he had to rediscount this bill. For the banks this amounted to a privilege of coining money. Messrs. Jones, Lloyd and Co. made payments in this way "from time immemorial," as soon as money was scarce and the rate of interest rose above 5%. The customer was glad to get such banker's bills because bills from Jones, Loyd and Co. were easier discounted than his own; besides, they often passed through twenty to thirty hands. (Ibid., Nos. 901 to 904, 905, 992.)

    All these forms serve to make the payments claim transferable.

       "There is scarcely any shape into which credit can be cast,
      in which it will not at times be called to perform the
      functions of money; and whether that shape be a bank-note,
      or a bill of exchange, or a banker's cheque, the process
      is in every essential particular the same, and the result
      is the same." Fullarton, On the Regulation of Currencies,
      2nd ed., London, 1845, p. 38. — "Bank-notes are the small
      change of credit" (p. 51).

    The following from J. W. Gilbart's The History and Principle of Banking, London, 1834:

       "The trading capital of a bank may be divided into two
      parts: the invested capital, and the borrowed banking
      capital" (p. 117). "There are three ways of raising a
      banking or borrowed capital. First, by receiving;
      secondly, by the issuing of notes; thirdly, by the drawing
      of bills. If a person will lend me £100 for nothing, and I
      lend that £100 to another person at four per cent interest,
      then, in the course of a year, I shall gain £4 by the
      transaction. Again, if a person will take my 'promise to
      pay'" ("I promise to pay" is the usual formula for English
      bank-notes) "and bring it back to me at the end of the year,
      and pay me four per cent for it, just the same as though I
      had lent him 100 sovereigns, then I shall gain £4 by that
      transaction; and again, if a person in a country town
      brings me £100 on condition that, twenty-one days afterwards,
      I shall pay the same amount to a person in London, then
      whatever interest I can make of the money during the
      twenty-one days, will be my profit. This is a fair
      representation of the operations of banking, and of the
      way in which a banking capital is created by means of
      deposits, notes, and bills" (p. 117). "The profits of a
      banker are generally in proportion to the amount of his
      banking or borrowed capital... To ascertain the real profit
      of a bank, the interest upon the invested capital should
      be deducted from the gross profit, and what remains is the
      banking profit" (p. 118). "The advances of bankers to
      their customers are made with other people's money"
      (p. 146). "Precisely those bankers who do not issue notes,
      create a banking capital by the discounting of bills.
      They render their discounts subservient to the increase
      of their deposits. The London bankers will not discount
      except for those houses who have deposit accounts with them"
      (p. 119). "A party who has had bills discounted, and has
      paid interest on the whole amount, must leave some portion of
      that amount in the hands of the banker without interest.
      By this means the banker obtains more than the current rate
      of interest on the money actually advanced, and raises a
      banking capital to the amount of the balance left in his
      hands" (pp. 119- 20).

    Economising on reserve funds, deposits, cheques:

       "Banks of deposit serve to economise the use of the
      circulating medium. This is done upon the principle of
      transfer of titles.... Thus it is that banks of deposit ...
      are enabled to settle a large amount of transactions
      with a small amount of money. The money thus liberated,
      is employed by the banker in making advances, by discount
      or otherwise, to his customers. Hence the principle of
      gives additional efficiency to the deposit system..." (p. 123). "
      It matters not whether the two parties, who have
      dealings with each other, keep their accounts with the
      same banker or with different bankers; for, as the
      bankers exchange their cheques with each other at the
      clearing house.... The deposit system might thus, by
      means of transfers, be carried to such an extent as wholly
      to supersede the use of a metallic currency. Were every man
      to keep a deposit account at a bank, and make all his
      payments by cheques, money might be superseded, and cheques
      become the sole circulating medium. In this case,
      however, it must be supposed that the banker has the money
      in his hands, or the cheques would have no value" (p. 124).

    Centralisation of local transactions in the hands of the banks is effected 1) through branch banks. Country banks have branch establishments in the smaller towns of their district, and London banks in different districts of the city. 2) Through agencies.

       "Each country banker employs a London agent to pay his
      notes or bills ... and to receive sums that may be lodged
      by parties residing in London for the use of parties residing
      in the country" (p.127). "Each banker accepts the notes
      of others, but does not reissue them. In all larger cities
      they come together once or twice a week and exchange their
      notes. The balance is paid by a draft on London" (p.134).
      "It is the object of banking to give facilities to trade,
      and whatever gives facilities to trade gives facilities to
      speculation. Trade and speculation are in some cases so
      nearly allied, that it is impossible to say at
      what precise point trade ends and speculation begins....
      Wherever there are banks, capital is more readily obtained,
      and at a cheaper rate. The cheapness of capital gives
      facilities to speculation, just in the same way as the
      cheapness of beef and of beer gives facilities to
      gluttony and drunkenness" (pp. 137, 438). "As banks of
      circulation always issue their own notes, it would seem that
      their discounting business was carried on exclusively
      with this last description of capital, but it is not so.
      It is very possible for a banker to issue his own notes for
      all the bills he discounts, and yet nine-tenths of the
      bills in his possession shall represent real capital.
      For, although in the first instance, the banker's
      notes are given for the bill, yet these notes may not stay in
      circulation until the bill becomes due — the bill may have
      three months to run, the notes may return in three days" (p. 172).
      "The overdrawing of a cash credit account is a regular matter
      of business; it is, in fact, the purpose for which the
      cash credit has been granted.... Cash credits are granted
      not only upon personal security, but also upon the security
      of the Public Funds" (pp. 174, 175). "Capital advanced,
      by way of loan, on the securities of merchandise, would
      produce the same effects as if advanced in the discounting
      of bills. If a party borrows 1400 on the security of his
      merchandise, it is the same as though he had sold his
      merchandise for a 8100 bill, and got it discounted with the
      banker. By obtaining this advance he is enabled to hold
      over this merchandise for a better market, and avoids a
      sacrifice which, otherwise, be might be induced to make,
      order to raise the money for urgent purposes" (pp. 180-81).

    The Currency Theory Reviewed, etc., pp. 62-63:

       "It is unquestionably true that the £1,000 which you deposit
      at A today may be reissued tomorrow, and form a
      deposit at B. The day after that, reissued from B, it may
      form a deposit at C ... and so on to infinitude; and that
      the same £1,000 in money may thus, by a succession of transfers,
      multiply itself into a sum of deposits absolutely
      indefinite. It is possible, therefore, that nine-
      tenths of all the deposits in the United Kingdom may have
      no existence beyond their record in the books of the
      bankers who are respectively accountable for them ...
      Thus in Scotland, for instance, currency (mostly paper
      money at that) has never exceeded £3 million, the deposits
      in the banks are estimated at £27 million.... Unless a run
      on the banks be made, the same £1,000 would, if sent
      back upon its travels, cancel with the same facility a sum
      equally indefinite. As the same £1,000 with which you
      cancel your debt to a tradesman today, may cancel his debt
      the merchant tomorrow, the merchant's debt to the
      bank the day following, and so on without end; so the same
      £1,000 may pass from hand to hand, and bank to bank, and
      cancel any conceivable sum of deposits."

    [We have seen that Gilbart knew even in 1834 that

       "whatever gives facilities to trade gives facilities to
      speculation. Trade and speculation are in some cases so
      nearly allied, that it is impossible to say at what
      precise point trade ends and speculation begins."

    The easier it is to obtain advances on unsold commodities, the more such advances are taken, and the greater the temptation to manufacture commodities, or dump already manufactured commodities in distant markets, just to obtain advances of money on them. To what extent the entire business world of a country may be seized by such swindling, and what it finally comes to, is amply illustrated by the history of English business during 1845-47. It shows us what credit can accomplish. Before passing on to the following examples, a few preliminary remarks.

    At the close of 1842 the pressure which English industry suffered almost uninterruptedly since 1837, began to lift. During the following two years foreign demand for English manufactured goods increased still more; 1845 and 1846 marked a period of greatest prosperity. In 1843 the Opium War had opened China to English commerce. The new market gave a new impetus to the further expansion of an expanding industry, particularly the cotton industry. "How can we ever produce too much? We have to clothe 300 million people," a Manchester manufacturer said to this writer at the time. But all the newly erected factory buildings, steam-engines, and spinning and weaving machines did not suffice to absorb the surplus-value pouring in from Lancashire. With the same zeal as was shown in expanding production, people engaged in building railways. The thirst for speculation of manufacturers and merchants at first found gratification in this field, and as early as in the summer of 1844. Stock was fully underwritten, i.e., so far as there was money to cover the initial payments. As for the rest, time would show! But when further payments were due — Question 1059, C. D. 1848/57, indicates that the capital invested in railways in 1846-47 amounted to £75 million — recourse had to be taken to credit, and in most cases the basic enterprises of the firm had also to bleed.

    And in most cases these basic enterprises were already over-burdened. The enticingly high profits had led to far more extensive operations than justified by the available liquid resources. Yet there was credit-easy to obtain and cheap. The bank discount rate stood low: 1¾ to 2¾% in 1844, less than 3% until October 1845, rising to 5% for a while (February 1846), then dropping again to 3¼% in December 1846. The Bank of England had an unheard-of supply of gold in its vaults. All inland quotations were higher than ever before. Why then allow this splendid opportunity to escape? Why not go in for all one was worth? Why not send all one could manufacture to foreign markets which pined for English goods? And why should not the manufacturer himself pocket the double gain arising from selling yarn and fabrics in the Far East, and the return cargo in England?

    Thus arose the system of mass consignments to India and China against advance payments, and this soon developed into a system of consignments purely for the sake of getting advances, as described in greater detail in the following notes, which led inevitably to over-flooding the markets and a crash.

    The crash was precipitated by the crop failure of 1846. England, and particularly Ireland, required enormous imports of foodstuffs, notably corn and potatoes. But the countries which supplied them could be paid with the products of English industry only to a very limited extent. Precious metals had to be given out. Gold worth at least nine million was sent abroad. Of this amount no less than seven and a half million came from the treasury of the Bank of England, whose freedom of action on the money-market was thereby considerably impaired. Other banks, whose reserves were deposited with the Bank of England and were practically identical with those of that Bank, were thus also compelled to curtail accommodation of money. The rapid and easy flow of payments was obstructed, first here and there, then generally. The banking discount rate, still 3 to 3½% in January 1847, rose to 7% in April, when the first panic broke out. The situation eased somewhat in the summer (6½%, 6%), but when the new crop failed as well panic broke out afresh and even more violently. The official minimum bank discount rose in October to 7 and in November to 10%; i.e., the overwhelming mass of bills of exchange was discountable only at outrageous rates of interest, or no longer discountable at all. The general cessation of payments caused the failure of several leading and very many medium-sized and small firms. The Bank itself was in danger due to the limitations imposed by the artful Bank Act of 1844. The government yielded to the general clamour and suspended the Bank Act on October 25, thereby eliminating the absurd legal fetters imposed on the Bank. Now it could throw its supply of bank-notes into circulation without hindrance. The credit of these bank-notes being in practice guaranteed by the credit of the nation, and thus unimpaired, the money stringency was thus instantly and decisively relieved. Naturally, quite a number of hopelessly enmeshed large and small firms failed nevertheless, but the peak of the crisis was overcome, the banking discount dropped to 5% in December, and in the course of 1848 a new wave of business activity began which took the edge off the revolutionary movements on the continent in 1849, and which inaugurated in the fifties an unprecedented industrial prosperity, but then ended again — in the crash of 1857. — F. E.]

    I. A document issued by the House of Lords in 1848 deals with the colossal depreciation of government paper and bonds during the 1847 crisis. According to it the depreciation of October 23, 1847, compared with the level in February of the same year, amounted to:

                            On English government bonds      £93,824,217
                            On dock and canal stock               £1,358,288
                            On railway stock                            £19,579,820
                            Total                                              £114,762,325

    II. With reference to the swindle in East Indian trade, in which drafts were no longer drawn because commodities were being bought, but rather commodities were bought to be able to make out discountable drafts convertible into money, the Manchester Guardian of November 24, 1847, remarks:

    Mr. A in London instructs a Mr. B to buy from the manufacturer C in Manchester commodities for shipment to a Mr. D in East India. B pays C in six months' drafts to be made out by C on B. B secures himself by six months' drafts on A. As soon as the goods are shipped A makes out six months' drafts on D against the mailed bill of lading.

       "The shipper and the co-signee were thus both put in
      possession of funds — months before they actually paid
      for the goods; and, very commonly, these bills were renewed
      at maturity, on pretence of affording time for the
      returns in a 'long trade'. Unfortunately, losses by
      such a trade, instead of leading to its contraction, led
      directly to its increase. The poorer men became, the
      greater need they had to purchase, in order to make up, by
      new advances, the capital they had lost on the past adventures.
      Purchases thus became, not a question of supply and
      demand, but the most important part of the finance
      operations of a firm labouring under difficulties. But
      this is only one side of the picture. What took place
      in reference to the export of goods at home, was taking
      place in the purchase and shipment of produce abroad. Houses
      in India, who had credit to pass their bills, were purchasers
      of sugar, indigo, silk, or cotton — not because the prices
      advised from London by the last overland mail promised a
      profit on the prices current in India, but because former
      drafts upon the London house would soon fall due, and must be
      provided for. What was so simple as to purchase a cargo of
      sugar, pay for it in bills upon the London house at ten
      months' date, transmit the shipping documents by
      the overland mail; and, in less than two months, the goods
      on the high seas, or perhaps not yet passed the mouth of
      the Hoogly, were pawned in Lombard Street — putting the
      house in funds eight months before the drafts against those
      goods fell due. And all this went on without interruption or
      difficulty, as long as bill-brokers had abundance of
      money 'at call,'; to advance on bills of lading and dock
      warrants, and to discount, without limit, the bills of India
      houses drawn upon the eminent firms in Mincing Lane."

    [This fraudulent procedure remained in vogue so long as goods to and from India had to round the Cape in sailing vessels. But ever since they are being shipped in steamboats via the Suez Canal this method of fabricating fictitious capital has been deprived of its basis — the long freight voyage. And ever since the telegraph informs the English businessman about the Indian market and the Indian merchant about the English market, on the same day this method has become totally impracticable. — F.E.]

    III. The following is taken from the quoted Report on Commercial Distress, 1847-48:

       "In the last week of April 1847, the Bank of England advised
      the Royal Bank of Liverpool that it would thereafter reduce
      its discount business with the latter bank by one-half.
      The announcement operated with peculiar hardship
      with peculiar hardship on this account, that the payments
      into Liverpool had latterly been much more in bills than
      in cash; and the merchants who generally brought to
      the Bank a large proportion of cash with which to pay
      their acceptances, had latterly been able to bring only
      bills which they had received for their cotton and other
      produce, and that Increased very rapidly as the difficulties
      increased.... The acceptances ... which the Bank had to
      pay for the merchants, were acceptances drawn chiefly
      upon them from abroad, and they have been accustomed to
      meet those acceptances by whatever payment they received for
      their produce.... The bills that the merchants brought...
      in lieu of cash, which they usually brought ... were
      of various dates, and of various descriptions; a considerable
      number of them were bankers' bills, of three months'
      date, the large bulk being cotton bills. These bills of
      exchange, when bankers' bills, were accepted by London
      bankers, and by merchants in every trade that we could mention
      — the Brazilian, the American, the Canadian, the West Indian....
      The merchants did not draw upon each other; but the parties
      in the interior, who had purchased produce from the merchants,
      remitted to the merchants bills on London bankers, or bills
      on various parties in London, or bills upon anybody. The
      announcement of the Bank of England caused a reduction
      of the maturity terms of bills drawn against sales of
      foreign products, frequently extending to over three
      months" (pp. 26, 27).

    The period of prosperity in England from 1844 to 1847, was, as described above, connected with the first great railway swindle. The above-named report makes the following reference to the effect of this swindle on business in general:

       In April 1847 "almost all mercantile houses had begun
      to starve their business more or less ... by taking part of
      their commercial capital for railways" (p.42). "Loans
      were made on railway shares at a high rate of interest, say,
      8%, by private individuals, by bankers and by fire-offices"
      (p. 66). "Loans to so great an extent by commercial
      houses to railways induced them to lean too much upon banks
      by the discount of paper, whereby to carry on their commercial
      operations" (p. 67). (Question:) "Should you say that the
      railway calls had had a great effect in producing the
      pressure which there was" (on the money-market) "in April
      and October" (1847)? — (Answer:) "I should say that they
      had had hardly any effect at all in producing the pressure
      in April; I should imagine that up to April, and up, perhaps,
      to the summer, they had increased the power of bankers in some
      respects rather than diminished it; for the expenditure had
      not been nearly so rapid as the calls; the consequence
      was, that most of the banks had rather a large amount of
      railway money in their hands in the beginning of the year."

    (This is corroborated in numerous statements made by bankers in C. D. 1848-57.)

       "In the summer that melted gradually away, and on the
      31st of December it was materially less. One cause ... of the
      pressure in October was the gradual diminution of the
      railway money in the bankers' hands; between the 22nd of
      April and the 31st of December the railway balances in our
      hands were reduced one- third; and the railway calls have also
      had this effect throughout the Kingdom; they have been
      gradually draining the deposits of bankers" (pp. 43, 44).

    Samuel Gurney (head of the ill-famed firm of Overend, Gurney and Co.) similarly says:

       "During the year 1846 ... there had been a considerable demand
      for capital, for the establishment of rail-ways ... but it did not
      increase the value of money.... There was a condensation of
      small sums into large masses, and those large masses were
      in our market; so that, upon the whole, the effect was to throw
      more money into the money-market of the City than to take it
      out" [p. 159].

    A. Hodgson, Director of the Liverpool Joint-Stock Bank, shows how much bills of exchange may constitute a reserve for bankers:

       "It has been our habit to keep at least nine-tenths of all
      our deposits, and all money we have of other persons,
      in our bill case, in bills that are falling due from day
      to day ... so much so, that during the time of the run, the
      bills falling due were almost equal to the amount of the
      ran upon us day by day" (p. 53).

    Speculative bills.

       "5092. Who were those bills (against sold cotton)
      generally accepted by?" — (R. Gardner, the cotton
      manufacturer repeatedly mentioned in this work:) "Produce
      brokers: a person buys cotton, and places it in the hands of
      a broker, and draws upon that broker, and gets the bills
      discounted." — "5094. And they are taken to the banks at
      Liverpool, and discounted? — Yes, and in other parts besides....
      I believe if it had not been for the accommodation thus
      granted, and principally by the Liverpool banks, cotton
      would never have been so high last year as it was by 1½ d.
      or 2d. a pound." — "600. You have stated that a vast amount
      of bills were put in circulation, drawn by speculators upon
      cotton brokers in Liverpool; does that system extend to your
      advance on acceptances upon colonial and foreign produce
      as well as on cotton?" (A. Hodgson, a Liverpool banker:)
      "It refers to all kinds of colonial produce, but to
      cotton most especially." — "601. Do you, as a banker,
      disencourage as far as you can that description of paper?
      — We do not; we consider it a very legitimate description of
      , when kept in moderation. This description of paper is
      frequently renewed."

    Swindling in the East Indian and Chinese Market, 1847. — Charles Turner (head of one of the leading East Indian houses in Liverpool):

       "We are all aware of the events which have taken place as
      regards the Mauritius trade, and other trades of that kind.
      The brokers have been in the habit ... not only of advancing
      upon goods after their arrival to meet the bills drawn against
      those goods, which is perfectly legitimate, and upon the
      bills of lading ... but ... they have advanced upon produce
      before it was shipped, and in some cases before it was
      manufactured. Now, to speak of my own individual instance:
      I have bought bills in Calcutta to the extent of six or seven
      thousand pounds in one particular instance; the proceeds of
      the bills went down to the Mauritius, to help in the
      growth of sugar; those bills came to England, and above half
      of them were protested; for when the shipments of sugar came
      forward, instead of being held to pay those bills, it had
      been mortgaged to third parties ... before it was shipped,
      in fact almost before it was boiled" (p.78). "Now
      manufacturers are insisting upon cash but it does not amount
      to much, because if a buyer has any credit in London, he
      can draw upon the house, and get the bill discounted; he
      goes to London, where discounts now are cheap; he gets
      the bill discounted, and pays cash to the manufacturer....
      It takes twelve months, at least, for the shipper of goods
      to get his return from India ... a man with ten or fifteen
      thousand pounds would go into the Indian trade; he would
      open a credit with a house in London, to a considerable
      extent, giving that house one per cent; he, drawing upon
      the house in London, on the understanding that the
      proceeds of the goods that go out are to be returned to the
      house in London, but it being perfectly understood by
      both parties that the man in London is to be kept out of
      a cash advance; that is to say, in other words, the bills are
      to be renewed till the proceeds come home. The bills were
      discounted at Liverpool, Manchester ... or in London
      ... many of them lie in the Scotch banks" (p. 79). — "786.
      There is one house which failed in London the other day,
      and in examining their affairs, a transaction of this sort
      was proved to have taken place; there is a house of business
      at Manchester, and another at Calcutta; they opened a
      credit account with a house in London to the extent of
      £200,000; that is to say, the friends of this house in
      Manchester, who consigned goods to the East India House from
      Glasgow and from Manchester, had the power of drawing upon
      the house in London to the extent of £200,000; at the same
      time, there was an understanding that the corresponding
      house in Calcutta were to draw upon the London house to
      the extent of £200,000; with the proceeds of those bills
      sold in Calcutta, they were to buy other bills, and remit them
      to the house in London, to take up the first bills drawn from
      Glasgow... There would have been £600,000 of bills created
      upon that transaction." — "971. At present, if a house in
      Calcutta purchase a cargo" (for England), "and give their
      own bills upon their correspondent in London in payment, and
      they send the bills of lading home to this country, those
      bills of lading ... immediately become available to them
      in Lombard Street for advances, and they have eight months'
      use of the money before their correspondents are called
      upon to pay."

    IV. In 1848 a secret committee of the House of Lords investigated the causes of the 1847 crisis. The evidence given to the committee was not published, however, until 1857 (Minutes of Evidence, taken before the Secret Committee of the H. of L. appointed to inquire into the Causes of Distress, etc., 1857; quoted as C.D. 1848/57). Here Mr. Lister, Director of the Union Bank of Liverpool, testified, among other things, to the following:

       "2444. In the spring of 1844 there was an undue
      extension of credit... because a man transferred property
      from business into railways and was still anxious to
      carry on the same extent of business. He probably
      first thought that he could sell the railway shares at a
      profit and replace the money in his business. Perhaps
      he found that could not be done, and he then got credit
      in his business where formerly he paid in cash. There was
      an extension of credit from that circumstance."

    "2500. Were those bills ... upon which the banks had sustained a loss by holding them, principally bills upon corn or bills upon cotton?"e; — "They were bills upon all kinds of produce, corn and cotton and sugar, all foreign produce of all descriptions. There was scarcely any thing perhaps with the exception of oil, that did not go down." — "2506. A broker who accepts a bill will not accept it without a good margin as to the value."

    "2512. There are two kinds of bills drawn against produce; the first is the original bill drawn abroad upon the merchant, who imports it.... The bills which are drawn against produce frequently fall due before the produce arrives. The merchant, therefore, when it arrives, if he has not sufficient capital, has to pledge that produce with the broker till he has time to sell that produce. Then anew species of bill is immediately drawn by the merchant in Liverpool upon the broker, on the security of that produce.... Then it is the business of the banker to ascertain from the broker whether he has the produce, and to what extent he has advanced upon it. It is his business to see that the broker has property to protect himself if he makes a loss."

    "2516. We also receive bills from abroad.... A man buys a bill abroad on England, and sends it to a house in England; we cannot tell whether that bill is drawn prudently or imprudently, whether it is drawn for produce or for wind."

    "2533. You said that almost every kind of foreign produce was sold at a great loss. Do you think that that was in consequence of undue speculation in that produce? — It arose from a very large import, and there not being an equal consumption to take it off. It appears that consumption fell off a great deal." — "2534. In October produce was almost unsaleable."

    How a general sauve qui peut develops at the height of a crisis is revealed in the same report by a first-rate expert, the esteemed crafty Quaker, Samuel Gurney, of Overend, Gurney and Co.:

       "1262 ... When a panic exists a man does not ask himself
      what he can get for his bank-notes, or whether he shall
      lose one or two per cent by selling his exchequer bills,
      or three per cent. If he is under the influence of alarm he
      does not care for the profit or loss, but makes himself
      safe and allows the rest of the world to do as they please."

    V. Concerning the mutual satiation of the two markets Mr. Alexander, a merchant in the East India trade, testifies before the Committee of the, Lower House on the Bank Act of 1857 (quoted as B.C. 1857):

       "4330. At the present moment, if I lay out 6s. in Manchester,
      I get 5s. back in India; if I lay out 6s. in India, I get 5s.
      back in London."

    So that the Indian market is, therefore, drugged by England, and the English by India. This was, indeed, the case in the summer of 1857, barely ten years after the bitter experience of 1847!